|
|||||||
Two-way
comparison between Monopoly & Cournot Duopoly using Cubic Cost Function: Conditions for Comparability & Feasibility of Equilibrium Outcomes |
|||||||
Paper Id :
19493 Submission Date :
2024-12-08 Acceptance Date :
2024-12-19 Publication Date :
2024-12-20
This is an open-access research paper/article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited. For verification of this paper, please visit on
http://www.socialresearchfoundation.com/remarking.php#8
|
|||||||
| |||||||
Abstract |
The paper compares the equilibrium outcomes of Monopoly and Cournot Duopoly using the linear demand function and cubic cost function. Given the limited literature available on the subject, emphasis is placed on the signs, range of values, and interrelationships between the various parameters of the cost and demand functions to compare the equilibrium outcomes of both market structures. In both cases, using identical demand and cost functions is meaningful when the equilibrium outcomes are feasible and all the non-negativity conditions are satisfied. |
||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Keywords | Monopoly, Cournot Duopoly, Cubic Cost Function, Equilibrium. | ||||||
Introduction | In the field of microeconomics, the study of various market
structures in a comparative manner
is quite common. For a student of economics, it is inevitable to study
all the basic market structure
(Varian, Hal, 2014), both perfectly competitive and imperfectly competitive. In general, there is a visible discrepancy
between the approaches to finding the equilibrium (Koutsoyiannis, 1989) outcome.
While studying it graphically, the cost curves
are taken as per the traditional cost theory that is ‘U’
shaped (strictly convex) (Sydsaeter et al., 2016) average cost (AC) and marginal cost (MC) (Varian,
Hal, 2014) curves are considered, whereas while addressing the same problem mathematically, some arbitrary cost
function ‘C(q)’ is used without
considering its exact nature. If an algebraic treatment becomes necessary, in
most of the cases (if not all), a
linear cost function (Eppstein et al, n.d.) is used. Surprisingly, this discrepancy is not found regarding the demand functions since they are considered to be linear,
irrespective of the market structure under study. |
||||||
Objective of study | The
paper undertakes the exercise by working on the equilibrium outcome of two
important imperfectly competitive
market structures, namely Monopoly and Duopoly (Ferguson, 1975) by considering cubic cost functions in both cases.
The paper is organised as follows: Section
2 defines the concepts of the
above-mentioned market structures and the available literature. Section 3 briefly explains the methodology
used. Section 4 deals with the primary algebraic analysis in three stages: studying
a cubic cost function, finding
a Monopoly and then a Cournot Duopoly
equilibrium outcome, and comparing the outcomes between
them. The paper concludes in Section 5. |
||||||
Review of Literature | Monopoly: A pure monopoly exists when only one producer (seller) exists in a market. There are no competitors or rivals. However, the policies of a monopolist may be constrained by the indirect competition of all commodities for the consumers’ money and of reasonably adequate substitute goods and by the threat of potential competition if market entry is possible (Ferguson, 1975). Duopoly: A simplification of oligopoly (few sellers’ market), where there are only two producers (sellers) selling an identical commodity (in our context). In such markets, strategic interaction among firms, hence rivalry, is clearly visible. Cournot Duopoly: A specific type of duopoly model named after the economist who proposed it (Cournot, 2020.) where the two firms simultaneously choose their profit-maximising outputs. Unfortunately, little could be gathered from the existing literature regarding the research question. Cubic cost functions are discussed quite in detail in Vali (2014), and the analysis in the first part of Section 4 of the paper uses a similar cubic cost function for both market structures. Later on, the cost function in Vali (2014) was used to find and analyse the equilibrium outcomes of a firm in a perfectly competitive market and for firms in a monopolistically competitive market. After an extensive search for research and articles regarding the same, only one relevant piece of literature was found- where, once again, the authors focused more on the graphical (Nikutowski et al., 2013) part and other intuitive questions rather than the algebra. Moreover, nothing similar could be found in the case of Duopoly. In light of the gaps observed during the literature review, the exercise to apply the cubic cost function along with the linear demand function in both forms of the market to find out their equilibrium outcomes and strike a comparison as far as possible was felt justified. Meanwhile, since the demand and cost function parameters in all the cases are arbitrary constants, it is meaningful to find out the signs and the range of values of the parameters and possible relationships between them, making the equilibrium outcomes comparable and feasible. |
||||||
Methodology | The methodology used is the universally applied optimisation (individual profit maximisation) technique. For the monopoly, the first order condition (F.O.C) (Sydsaeter et al., 2016) for optimisation is MR = MC to determine equilibrium output, and based on that output, equilibrium price and profit would be calculated by standard formulae. The second order condition (S.O.C) (Sydsaeter et al., 2016) for the same, i.e. this equilibrium should be on the rising portion of the MC curve, is also verified. In Cournot Duopoly, the same optimisation technique is used in a simultaneous move game, where the two firms choose their profit-maximising output levels simultaneously. The equilibrium (Nash Equilibrium) occurs where the Best Response Function (BRF) (Osborne, 2009) of both firms has a meaningful intersection, that is, an intersection where the equilibrium output occurs on the rising portion of their MC Curves. Finally, for comparability, the same linear demand function and the same cubic cost function are considered for firms in both the market structures considered here. |
||||||
Analysis |
Ideally, the total duopoly profit should be less than the monopoly profit with identical demand and cost conditions (as has been done here), but in the present context with a cubic cost function, it will be really difficult to compare them. |
||||||
Conclusion |
Now, with the obtained results and the way they are obtained, it becomes quite clear why there is hardly any work towards this approach. Algebra is complicated, and it gradually gets more challenging to get a very clear picture of the meaningfulness of the results, especially when comparing them. In the paper, the relationship between the parameter in the demand function) and the parameter g (in the cost function) turned out to be crucial for comparability between these market structures; that is, the relationship must hold for positive profits in both markets. Finally, there is scope for further studies to explore similar analyses in other market structures using a cubic cost function. |
||||||
References |
|