ISSN: 2456–5474 RNI No.  UPBIL/2016/68367 VOL.- VII , ISSUE- X November  - 2022
Innovation The Research Concept
Democratic Decentralisation and Its Relationship with Central Government
Paper Id :  16672   Submission Date :  2022-11-06   Acceptance Date :  2022-11-19   Publication Date :  2022-11-21
This is an open-access research paper/article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited.
For verification of this paper, please visit on http://www.socialresearchfoundation.com/innovation.php#8
Mohan Lal Goswami
Assistant Professor
Political Science
Government Girls College,
Hanumangarh,Rajasthan, India
Abstract
Democracy is regarded as being one of the greatest types of government because it guarantees the freedom of opinion, expression, belief, faith, and worship, as well as terms of equality and possibility and the ability to join in political decision-making. The principle of democracy is the participation and control of the people in governance. Such involvement is only conceivable if the state's powers are decentralised to the district, block, and community levels, where all segments of the population can gather, discuss their problems, propose solutions, and plan, execute, and monitor implementation. Of the broadcasts, it’s referred to as the main thrust of democratic decentralisation. The transfer of planning, decision-making or governmental prerogatives out from centralised administration to its field organisations, relevant governmental units, semi-autonomous organizations, local governments, or non-governmental organisations is referred to as decentralisation. Different types of decentralisations can be largely characterised by the degree to which authority. Simply put, under decentralisation, authority is dispersed to relatively small government agencies rather than being focused at the center.
Keywords Democratic, Decentralisation, Organisation, Central Government, Authority.
Introduction
Over the last three decades, democracy has spread worldwide as a fundamental value and framework for governance. Decentralisation is also becoming more widely considered a necessary democratic principle. It wasn't enough for people to be able to vote for about three national leaders in free and fair elections regularly. (Jacoby, 2017) A good democracy in a country of relatively large size demands that employees be able to appoint their community officials and delegates, and these local authorities have had some real capacity to react to the people's needs. In short, decentralisation is progressively being demanded from underneath, through grassroots pressure, and is welcomed for its possibility to deepen and legitimize democracy. Finally, decentralisation of power adds another check against abuse of power. After all, furthermore, internal checks and balances are required within the central government. This is why a self-governing parliament as well as the judiciary, as well as effective auditing and anti-corruption mechanisms, are required. (Quinoas and Democratic Government, 1995)
Objective of study
The research aimed to fulfill the following objectives: 1. To explain the decentralisation 2. List the basic type of administrative decentralisation 3. To study the process of decentralisation 4. To study what the impact does decentralisation is on civil reform 5. To study Adapting to Decentralisation: Overarching Principles for Nation Strategies 6. To study Decentralized Governance Accountability, Transparency, and Corruption 7. this system works and how been managed by the organization 8. To study Corruption and Transparency.
Review of Literature

Define Decentralisation

Decentralisation aims to spread power, accountability, and finances for improving access among branches of government. It is the delegation of accountability for some public duties from the centralized government agencies to subordinate units of government entities, subordinate units or tiers of governments, semi-autonomous government authorities or companies, or area-wide, regional, or functional authorities.

Decentralisation has the potential to improve access to services, customize government actions to private demands, and expand chances for state-society interactions. (Rackley, 2006) Subnational governments, on the other hand, will be effective only if they have access to the requisite personnel and economic support to carry out the functions with that they've been entrusted.

Since the initiation of the Gram panchayat in 1959, gross roots leadership has been a main consideration of the Indian planning process. The essence of democratic decentralisation that has evolved is only being practiced in a limited way. It is recognized that India's development efforts didn't even address equity issues and poor development. As a result, there's a need to refocus development efforts on the poor and those at the grassroots. The 73rd amendment of the constitution Acts of India was a significant step toward decentralized governance. The 73rd Constitutional Amendment Act addresses reform measures in rural local governments, whereas the 74th Constitutional Amendment Act addresses reforms in urban local governments. (Shore, 2011) These amendments granted rural and urban local governments constitutional recognition. The Acts seek to formalize the concept of people's participation in strategic planning on the one hand and to devolve responsibility to society taken by an individual on the other. These acts addressed the long-standing issues of irregular elections, suppression, insufficient depiction, insufficient devolved powers of powers, a lack of accounting and management autonomy, as well a shortage of resources.

Each of the three basic types of administrative decentralisation – deconcentration, delegations, and devolution – has distinct characteristics.

a)     Deconcentration

Deconcentration, which is widely utilized in unitary systems and is typically seen as the weakest type of decentralisation, redistributes decision-making authority as well as financial and managerial duties among multiple stages of the central government. It can simply delegate authority from central governments in the country's capital to those operating in regions, provinces, or districts, or it can build strong field administrations or relevant administrative capability underneath the oversight of government agencies. (Vabo and Aars, 2013)

b)     Delegation

Delegation is a broader definition of decentralisation. Central governments delegate responsibility for decision-making as well as efficiency of government functions to semi-autonomous organizations that are not completely regulated by the government but are ultimately accountable to it. When governments establish public enterprises or companies, housing authorities, transport officials, special service systems, semi-autonomous public schools, regional economic organizations, or special implementation units, they delegate tasks. Typically, these groups have a tremendous level of leeway in making decisions. (Pratchett, 1999) They may well be exempt from the limits that apply to normal public servants who may be capable of charging user information for services.

There is a distinction to be made between democratic decentralisation and delegation. Delegation refers to the transfer of jurisdiction from a supervisor to a subordinate, which is done not as a right but also as a derived concession and is also done at the superior's discretion. 'Democratic decentralisation,' on the other hand, refers to a superior granting authority to a subsidiary as a privilege to be cherished by the subordinate rather than a concession. The term "democratic decentralisation" refers to an augmentation of the democratic principle that aims to broaden the area of people's participation and authority through delegation or devolution of power and influence to people's representative organizations from the highest to lowest levels in all 3 dimensions of strategic decision, financial control, and administrative structure with the least interference. (Bevir, 2011)


Decentralisation without democracy in some regions is shown below n table1:-

Distance regional border in (km)

Region or area that is decentralized 

Region or area that is not decentralized 

52

52

20

25

245

102

32

452

203

c. Devolution

Devolution is a third kind of administrative decentralisation. When governments delegate functions, they delegate authority over decision-making, financing, and administration to quasi-autonomous entities of local authorities with corporate status. Devolution often shifts service duties to municipalities, which choose their respective mayors or legislatures, raise their funds, and have autonomous ability to make investment strategies. Local governments have distinct and legally recognized geographical borders as to which they exert control and execute public responsibilities under a devolved system. (Gray and Jenkins, 1999) Most political decentralisation is based on this form of administrative decentralisation.

Through deconcentration and devolution, decentralisation empowers the local people. Decentralized governance aims to tap into local initiatives and practices by involving grassroots organizations like self-help groups. Decentralized governance enables both representative democracy and participatory democracy.

Another key feature of decentralisation is interactive policy formulation, which leads to decentralized decision-making. The interactive policy is a process in which the government but instead non-governmental sectors, such as the private sector, non-governmental organizations, communities, grass-roots organizations, and pressure groups, all participate in decision-making to influence issues and propose alternatives. As a result, decentralized governance is an alternative development strategy that is people-centered, participatory, and bottom-up. (WALDRON-MOORE, 1999)

Main Text

The Decentralisation processes

 Power is divided regionally and administratively: Power and work locations will unavoidably shift as a result of decentralisation. Issues relating to statute, prestige, and inadequate labor mobility sometimes obstruct movement regionally or among tiers of government. De-legitimating of a central state and the growth of representative governance at the local or intermediate levels of the government, for example, has impacted human resource allocation in Eastern European transition economies. To create flexibility, incentive programmers and procedures for cross-functional and cross-movement, which add to the costs of decentralisation, may be necessary. (Democratic Legal Studies Association, 2012)

Decentralisation expands prospects for regional autonomy as well as responsiveness to more specialized constituents, but it also provides sub-national governments greater room to fail if particular actions to improve local technical and administrative capability are not done.

Scaling economies/expertise groupings can be dispersed: The requirement for specialist employees is connected, in part, to the extent of the entity's area. Having experts or technical people below a specific size may be detrimental or inefficient. (Jacoby, 2017) Some approaches may be taken to solve this issue, and the other is to allow local self-government units to create organizations and invest their money to cover tasks that need specialized employees within the context of decentralisation programmers.

Increases the number of levels in the state: Decentralisation, particularly political decentralisation, generates a category of government servants that could have different priorities than employees at the very next higher level based on the unique information they get. This difference in opinions and convictions has the potential to cause conflict within the public service, which will necessitate efficient conflict resolution methods. (Shen, 1982)

This causes a conflict between local sovereignty and national standards: Decentralisation loosens national authority and opens the door to more regional diversity in public service conditions. Some leeway permits regions to recruit civil servants who are a good fit for their community's requirements and financial limits. National compensation, eligibility, and performance criteria can assure consistency in quality, but they can also result in human costs (particularly for locally managed healthcare and education). In addition to some local capacities, grant transmission systems will also need to account for various funding capacities in these and many other types of required expenditures. Decentralized states have identical terms and conditions for government personnel in different areas including the Philippines, Cambodia, and Pakistan. (Armstrong, 1999)

Creating extra branches of the government is a costly undertaking, and although the government may lower its function and lose staff in the framework of decentralisation, empirical data reveals that these individuals are frequently absorbed into the body by local governments. As a result, there is no net shift in public employment creation. In the worst-case scenario, central got employment remains constant whereas local authority employment increases.

Decentralisation and Civil Service Reform

Governmental reform is typically used as a supplement to the broader decentralisation of government activities or service delivery. Decentralizing the public service is not done for the sake of decentralisation; rather, it is made to better service delivery, manage resources more effectively, or support other broad result goals. This public service as a whole should be viewed as one of the primary means through which the government executes its responsibilities. Because of decentralisation, this instrument is frequently reconfigured to fulfill a new set of functions efficiently, fairly, and successfully. (Wilson, 1994) Thus, civil service reform is the process of changing laws and incentives to achieve a more efficient, devoted, and functioning government workforce in a more decentralized manner. This brief will first address the numerous civil service difficulties raised by sectoral or overall decentralisation schemes. It will then concentrate on several reform goals to deal with the changes that decentralisation might bring.

What impact does decentralisation have on the civil service?

To provide quality services to its residents, civil services throughout all branches of administration require a qualified, motivated, and efficient workforce. Traditional bureaucratic structures must be restructured as duties and responsibilities vary when public service operations and structures are delegated. As a result, decentralisation raises the need for qualified employees and emphasizes the necessity of capacity-building initiatives and


Decentralisation will be aided by civil service reform

The key considerations in evaluating public service reform goals are similar to those who are in more general decentralisation policies: Under what circumstances should human resources or organizational duties be decentralized or devolved to lower levels of government? What capacity is required in various areas to achieve a system more efficiently?

Even when resources allow for extensive training and all stakeholders support the reforms, the twin responsibilities of increasing local capacity and reacting to adjustments in intergovernmental coordinating demands may be challenging. (On the People's Democratic Dictatorship and the People's Democratic Legal System, 1969) The more common reality of financial limits and uneven support, on the other hand, practically assure that massive reform will be a long-drawn-out, expensive process that falls behind the speed of service or sector decentralisation.

Increasing Local Capacity

One of the most critical components in developing a well-functioning decentralized public service is localized (or at least sub-national) competence. In nations wherein community organizations already exist, the task will be to develop their institutional and legal foundations, as well as their human resource management skills. In regions wherein local government entities are in their infancy or exist only informally, the regulatory and administrative framework must be established before any sort of administration reform can be done.

The type of human-resource management methods that are practical and desirable is determined by the level of local capacity. Decentralisation of management of human resources is more likely to work when lower-level administrations have the managerial and financial resources to provide competitive pay packages and wage levels that attract homegrown talent. In many circumstances, the benefits of enabling local governments to determine hiring levels may exceed the danger of creating inter-regional inequities. (Souza, 1994) Because talent, as well as skills, is scarce at the local and state level, a centralized recruiting approach may be preferable to guarantee that the requisite talents are available in all regions. In circumstances when the center retains significant influence over human resources, care should be taken to ensure that local stakeholders' management options are not limited.

Adapting to Decentralisation: Overarching Principles for Nation Strategies

Responsibilities and standards should be clearly defined in the legal framework. The development of a strong legal framework to discuss problems associated with financial and reporting, determining the type of system processes (especially financial) that have been required and who can take responsibility for them, evaluating hiring practices and compensation schemes, and addressing issues related to public works procurement must have been a priority in any modernization effort to ensure sound use of government resources and minimize corruption.

Consistency and openness are gaining popularity. It is critical to guarantee openness in questions of employment, remuneration, and monitoring of local administration, and, most significantly, in the delivery of services. Changes in administration (and hence the civil service) should not be viewed as a tool to disenfranchise certain groups or favor others.

Mechanisms for reporting must be clear and exact. Clear reporting processes must be established concerning central governments (central government in the case of regional administration, and horizontally concerning other government entities at the same level). Audit courts can become a useful regulatory system in the long run. Shifts from the established system to new systems must be carefully planned to avoid conflicts among both current reporting arrangements and long-term mechanisms. (Modulation, 2004) Channels of contact between citizens and government servants must be established. Decentralisation increases the likelihood of tension between public officials and people by including more persons in the process of evaluating civil service performance. Private interest groups' harassment can impede honest and devoted government workers from executing their tasks, and civil servants can exploit their positions to intimidate people. These conflicts can be prevented by using relatively rapid and low-cost processes and mechanisms for resolving concerns, whether they are raised by government officials or people.

Training should help to foster the development of new working connections. Training can be used to create personal networks across different levels of government, locations, or varieties of government workers, in addition to increasing local capability. One idea, for example, may be to teach career civil workers and local elected officials together to assure that they better grasp what is required of them now and how much they can anticipate from one another.

All branches of government should indeed be incentivized to designate and plan for the sorts of people required to carry out new tasks. In the near run, these kinds of basic plans can assist minimize duplicate personnel, wasteful hiring, and other costly blunders by substituting for the computerized establishment management capabilities and human resource management professionals that so many nations lack. They can, at the absolute least, be an exercise in long-term planning and role description. (Lee-Geiller and Lee, 2019)

Decentralized Governance Accountability, Transparency, and Corruption

Accountability

Decentralisation, as it is now envisioned and increasingly applied in the global development sector, includes two major components: engagement and responsibility. Participation is primarily concerned with expanding residents' roles in selecting their community officials and informing that leadership doing other words, offering inputs towards local governance. The flip side of the process is accountability; it is the extent to which local governments must explain or defend how much they have accomplished or failed to achieve. One of the putative benefits of decentralisation is better knowledge about localized needs and preferences, however, there is no assurance that authorities will act on these desires unless they are held accountable to voters. Council elections are by far the most popular and influential form of governance, but other processes, such as city councils, have little sway. (What is democratic government? 1974)

Accountability may be viewed as the justification of involvement, in which the amount to which individuals could use engagement to hold a regional government accountable for its activities determines whether or not efforts to enhance participation are effective.

Accountability Types

Accountability exists in two dimensions: accountability of government employees to elected officials and accountability of elected officials to the public who elect them.

From Government Employees to Local Officials

The first kind can be difficult to implement since government workers, particularly experts in subjects such as health, education, and agriculture – it’s very sectors that are frequently decentralized – have a strong motive to avoid supervision by locally elected authorities. Such people typically have a university education and sophisticated lifestyle patterns that are difficult to sustain in towns and villages, job objectives that extend beyond the local and state level, and educational expectations for their children that school systems cannot achieve. They may also be concerned that if service delivery is localized, quality standards may decline. Finally, they frequently discover that the potential for corruption is larger when they are overseen by distant managers via extensive chains of command rather than when they should submit to supervisors near at hand. For all of these reasons, they are compelled to preserve relations with their parental departments in the centralized administration and to oppose decentralisation measures. (Yongmin Kim, 2010) And, unsurprisingly, their coworkers at the center have a vested interest in protecting these links, since they are concerned with upholding government standards in the delivery of services while also looking for possibilities for venality.

Given all of these good and bad reasons for opposition, it is hardly surprising that decentralisation initiatives frequently face massive bureaucratic rigidity, and designers are under pressure to maintain core networks between the sector and the central ministries, particularly on issues such as postings, promos, and salaries. Such links tend to undermine elected politicians' ability to monitor government employees ostensibly working for them. Some decentralized governance systems (for example, Bangalore State in India) seem to have resolved these issues to build public control over the bureaucracy, although it appears to have taken a long time.

Citizens Have Chosen Elected Leaders

The second form of responsibility is that which elected leaders have to the people. Elections (assuming they are open and fair) are the most visible form of accountability, but they are a very blunt instrument, used only at regular intervals and providing only the widest voter control over the government. (Kákai, 2021) Voters can choose to keep or fire their governors, which can have a positive impact on government, However, they are overall assessments, not responses to specific acts or omissions. And when municipal elections do center on a specific topic, such as schools, everything else is always left out of the equation. Citizens require more discerning tools to impose responsibility. Fortunately, there are a lot of these.

1.  When political parties are well-established and active at the local scale, as in many other Latin American nations, they may be a potent weapon for accountability. They have an inherent motive to identify and publicize misbehavior by the ruling party, as well as to continually offer voters an alternate set of public policies.

2. Citizens may use civil society and social capital to express their dissatisfaction with local got and persuade authorities to be more responsive. These representations are often provided by non-governmental organizations (NGOs) (though spontaneously demonstrations can sometimes be termed civil society), and, like political parties, frequently have parent organizations at the provincial level.

3. Citizens should be able to easily find out what their government is doing if they are to hold it responsible. At the local level, networking may be enough to disseminate such knowledge, but at any greater level, some type of media becomes necessary. Print media can serve this purpose in some nations, but their reach is limited outside of major population centers. (KE, HOLLINGWORTH and NESS, 2012) Reduced Fm television, which is very local, inexpensive to run, and may provide news and conversation programming addressing local topics, is a viable option in many circumstances.

4. Public meetings may be an excellent tool for motivating residents to voice their opinions and requiring public authorities to respond to them. Conferences may be as little as briefing sessions in certain cases, but they may help persuade public officials to justify their actions in others.

5. Some decentralisation projects have included formal redress procedures as an accountability measure. Bolivia most likely possesses the most sophisticated mechanism along similar lines, including its municipal Vigilance Committees, which are associated with traditional local social organizations and are tasked with monitoring elected councils and are encouraged to submit actual grievances with elevated amounts if necessary.  Citizens who are displeased with their authorities can use formal recall procedures in other systems.

6. Opinion polls have traditionally been thought to be too complex and sophisticated to be used at the local level, but in the Philippines, useable and accessible technologies are being developed, allowing local-level NGOs to utilize such polls to analyze public opinion on service provision.

7. According to a recent USAID study of democratic local administration in six countries, each nation used a different combination of these procedures, and no country used them all together. (Page and Goldsmith, 1985) Although no one instrument was successful in all 6 settings, many combinations showed great potential. Some will be able to fill in for others who are unable or unwilling to do so. Civil society and media, for instance, may be able to compensate for a weak local party system.



Corruption and Transparency

In principle, these two characteristics should be inversely connected, with more openness in local administration implying less opportunity for corruption, since dishonest behavior would have become more easily recognized, penalized, and avoided in the future. The experience of the industrialized nations suggests that this is true in the long run, but recent experience reveals that somehow this correlation is not always true in the short run. Local government systems in former Soviet nations, for example, became considerably more accessible to the people inspection in the 1990s; however, there is no question that wrongdoing at all stages has expanded significantly. It is hoped that the above-mentioned local accountability systems would be implemented. It is intended that the above-mentioned local accountability systems, along with improved credibility at the national level, would raise the level of truthfulness at all levels, although this will take time at best. (Ferraresi and Gucciardi, 2021) The message to the current international system is to implement as some of these standards as possible.

The second version of the link between accountability and corruption has been observed in India, where, while greater transparency throughout local governance did not result in significant corrupt practices, it led to cultural expectations of broad public gross incompetence simply even though citizens have become more aware of what was happening on. This process has undoubtedly reproduced itself in several other locations. Citizens should recognize the progress made as accountability systems become more effective and corruption continues to diminish.

Methodology
Methodology Capacity-building at all levels of government is widely acknowledged to be a vital component of decentralisation. The chronology and emphasis levels of training—for example, whether to teach local and central government’s first—depending on the country, however, sub-national governments have traditionally been the first to be taught to assume their new obligations. There are fewer consensuses on how to provide the proper human resource package to the essential levels of government, as well as how to integrate human resources across and also between tiers of government. The option to decentralize or keep centralized authority over the management of human resources (recruiting, hiring, compensation setting, etc.) is significantly influenced by the level of sub-national capability that exists.
Conclusion
Many nations democratic local governance projects offer great potential for building successful mechanisms of government oversight that will guarantee that government personnel are accountable to elected representatives and that the latter are accountable to the people that engaged them in the first place. In the process, these accountability measures should enhance the push for more transparency in local administration, making corruption simpler to expose and thereby restrict. It took decades for similar initiatives to achieve significant progress in the industrialized world, thus too rapid results can indeed be envisaged elsewhere. The most important issues in development discourse are decentralisation and democracy. The movement of planning, decision-making, or administrative authority from the centralized administration to its field agencies is referred to as decentralisation. Democratic decentralisation is an expansion of the democratic ideal that strives to broaden the area of people's involvement, authority, and autonomy through power devolution to people's representative groups. The global phenomenon of democratic decentralisation the 73rd and 74th Amendment To the constitution Acts of India expanded the scope of democratic decentralisation in both rural and urban regions. Acts have formalized citizen engagement through grime and ward committees. A notable characteristic of these modifications is the creation of a new era of administration at the local level for women and underprivileged groups of society. Amendments have helped to introduce real democracy to the local level.
References
1. Jacoby, W. (2017), Grand Coalitions and Democratic Dysfunction: Two Warnings from Central Europe. Government and Opposition, 52(2), pp.329-355. 2. Rackley, E. (2006), The Democratic Republic of the Congo: undoing government by predation. Disasters, 30(4), pp.418-432. 3. Shore, C. (2011), ‘European Governance’ or Governmentality? The European Commission and the Future of Democratic Government. European Law Journal, 17(3), pp.287-303. 4. Vabo, S. and Aars, J. (2013), New Public Management Reforms and Democratic Legitimacy: Notions of Democratic Legitimacy among West European Local Councilors. Local Government Studies, 39(5), pp.703-720. 5. Pratchett, L. (1999), Introduction: Defining democratic renewal. Local Government Studies, 25(4), pp.1-18. 6. Bevir, M. (2011), Democratic Governance: A Genealogy. Local Government Studies, 37(1), pp.3-17. 7. Gray, A. and Jenkins, B. (1999), Democratic renewal in local government: Continuity and change. Local Government Studies, 25(4), pp.26-45. 8. WALDRON-MOORE, P (1999), Eastern Europe at the Crossroads of Democratic Transition. Comparative Political Studies, 32(1), pp.32-62. 9. WALDRON-MOORE, P (1999), Eastern Europe at the Crossroads of Democratic Transition. Comparative Political Studies, 32(1), pp.32-62. 10.Democratic Legal Studies Association (2012), Denouncing the Joint Crackdown of Government against Unregistered Immigrants Democratic Legal Studies, null(49), pp.377-379. 11. Shen, F (1982), On Democratic Institutionalization. Chinese Law & Government, 15(3-4), pp.124-133. 12. Armstrong, H (1999), The key themes of democratic renewal. Local Government Studies, 25(4), pp.19-25. 13. Wilson, D. (1994) Facing up to the ‘democratic deficit’. Local Government Studies, 20(2), pp.193-201. 14. Chinese Law & Government (1969), On the People's Democratic Dictatorship and the People's Democratic Legal System. 2(2), pp.3-61. 15. Souza, C. (1994) Political and financial decentralisation in democratic Brazil. Local Government Studies, 20(4), pp.588-609. 16. Moulaison, H (2004), The Minitel and France's legacy of democratic information access. Government Information Quarterly, 21(1), 2004, pp.99-107. 17. Lee-Geiller, S. and Lee, T. (2019) Using government websites to enhance democratic E-governance: A conceptual model for evaluation. Government Information Quarterly, 36(2), pp.208-225. 18. Yongmin Kim(2010), Comparative Analysis of Japanese Foreign Policy towards East-Sea Rim Countries by the New Democratic Party Government: Comparing with Previous Liberal Democratic Party Governments. Comparative Democratic Studies, 6(1), pp.109-139. 19. Kákai, L. (2021) Centralization in one step. Centralization and decentralisation in Hungary from a public services perspective. Politics in Central Europe, 17(s1), pp.703-728. 20. KE, K., HOLLINGWORTH, W., and NESS, A. (2012) The costs of centralization: a systematic review of the economic impact of the centralization of cancer services. European Journal of Cancer Care, 21(2), pp.158-168. 21. Page, E., and Goldsmith, M. (1985) Centralization and Decentralisation: A Framework for Comparative Analysis. Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy, 3(2), pp.175-185. 22. Ferraresi, M. and Gucciardi, G. (2021) Political alignment, centralization, and the sense of government unpreparedness during the COVID-19 pandemic. European Journal of Political Economy, p.102144.